Categories: Bitcoin Latest News

The Future On A Bitcoin Standard — Bitcoin Is Not Democratic Part Four

The death of Democracy is around the corner — what will replace it? As Bitcoin changes the very fabric of society, we’ll need new modes of governance and coexistence.

With each new installment of this series, the Clown World simulation takes it up a notch.

Part Three kicked off with the stupidity happening in Canada.

Part Four is now being written right in the midst of a geopolitical clusterfuck in which every side is lying, maneuvering and propagandizing, while innocent individuals who just want to live in peace are being terrorized, displaced and killed.

Anyone who still has faith in modern “governments” of any kind at this point is beyond help.

This madness is all a function of the “representative state.” I don’t care if it’s Russia, NATO, the U.S., the EU or Ukraine itself. None of these entities are innocent. Only the individuals and families living within their bullshit borders are.

Volodymyr Zelensky is just as guilty as Vladimir Putin. He and his recently-discovered $1.2 billion in an offshore account, are a prime example of how “democratically elected representatives” simply use the very people they’re supposed to serve, for their own ends. Whilst innocent people die, he’s posing for photos, making deals with other politicians and literally acting with Sean Penn. While his people are locked out of the financial system, he and his cronies’ salaries are being paid by the wealth confiscated via taxes from those same people.

None of the decision-makers, on any side, are actually being displaced, killed, shot at or experiencing the destruction of their livelihoods. The talking heads, politicians and so-called “human rights” charlatans like Garry Kasparov, are openly calling for war because they have NO personal skin in the game.

The only human rights these frauds believe in are the ones they get funded to turn into propaganda. And they’ll play hawk over social media like little keyboard warriors, in the hopes to spark a larger war so that they can point the finger and say: “See. I was right.”

Absolute egomaniacs.

Hey Kasparov, if you want war, how about you go fight it yourself?

This continued madness is all a function of “rulers” and their pet “presenters” experiencing no consequence for their actions. If anything, the only “consequence” is personal enrichment.

The ends which they play all of these games for just happen to include you and I as expendable pawns, and when the price for one’s enrichment is somebody else’s blood, you can be almost certain that blood will be spilled.

The following passage from Nassim Taleb’s “Skin in the Game” shines an abundantly clear light on this, and reminds us why the current version of madness in Russia/Ukraine (or for that matter, any other modern war) not only exists, but why it’s in fact a historical aberration:

“…owning one’s risk was an inescapable moral code for the past four millennia, until very recent times. Warmongers were required to be warriors. Fewer than a third of Roman emperors died in their bed (assuming those weren’t skillfully poisoned). Status came with increased exposure to risk: Alexander, Hannibal, Scipio, and Napoleon were not only first in battle, but derived their authority from a disproportionate exhibition of courage in previous campaigns. Courage is the only virtue that can’t be faked (or gamed like metrics). Lords and knights were individuals who traded their courage for status, as their social contract was an obligation to protect those who granted them their status. This primacy of the risk-taker, whether warrior (or, critically, merchant), prevailed almost all the time in almost every human civilization; exceptions, such as Pharaonic Egypt or Ming China, in which the bureaucrat-scholar moved to the top of the pecking order were followed by collapse.” — Nassim Taleb

We’ll expand on this in the “Monarchies” section below, but suffice it to say that you won’t see these representatives bring the battle to their doorstep. They’ll be sending emails from their cushy home-office in the Hamptons while drawing a salary, paid for by you, and receiving “donations” from the cronies currently profiteering.

In fact, that’s the worst part of this entire madness. Modern governments continue to play these games because we’re not only stupid enough to assign them that “right,” but we also pay them for it!

Should we make it through the Great Filter, our descendants will shake their heads at the stupidity that non-economic, democratic governance was.

I look forward to an age where responsibility and consequence are reintroduced, where power is concentrated in distributed, competitive nodes, and democracy is but a memory. I have faith that Bitcoin will accomplish that, and change the course of human development “forever … Laura … forever.”

Monarchies

Skin in the game is what makes monarchies superior to democracies, or any other modern, representative-run state.

The point illustrated above by Taleb makes a resounding case for monarchy > democracy alone, but let us delve further:

Monarchies, in the more traditional sense (not so much the lizardry of modernity) are run by a private property owner (albeit a large one). As a result, their property is their capital and its preservation is naturally incentivised. Yes, a moron monarch may make poor decisions and burn through the capital in exchange for “present cash flow,” but the base tendency is otherwise. The converse is true for representative dEmOcRaCiEs as we outlined in parts One and Two of the series.The hereditary nature of monarchies is also an advantage. It’s a localized concentration of power more easily held accountable, and when combined with private property incentives, should produce more just “leaders” than the popularity contest winners in a democracy who will lie, cheat, steal and do anything to get into power.Numbers 1 and 2 above combined with skin in the game incline monarchs toward longer-term decision-making for the preservation of their private property, for their economic viability and for the continuation of their hereditary lineage. This lower time preference and proximity to economic consequences create a superior environment for sensible monetary policy, taxation and legislation (notwithstanding the inherent stupidity of all three).

These factors remind me of a passage from Hans-Herman Hoppe’s; “Democracy, The God That Failed.”

“Historically, the selection of a prince was through the accident of his noble birth, and his only personal qualification was typically his upbringing as a future prince and preserver of the dynasty and its status and possessions. This did not assure that a prince would not be bad and dangerous, of course. However, it is worth remembering that any prince who failed in his primary duty of preserving the dynasty, who wrecked or ruined the country, caused civil unrest, turmoil and strife, or otherwise endangered the position of the dynasty faced the immediate risk of either being neutralized or assassinated by another member of his own family.

“On the flip side, with a strong education and a princely upbringing, a monarch was far more inclined to be a functional ruler than the kind of character who rises through the political ranks of a democracy.” — Hoppe

Note that like Hoppe, I neither suggest we go back to monarchies, nor defend taxation, monetary policy or legislation of any kind. I merely present it here to compare the natural tendencies present in monarchies versus democracies (or other representative governments).

There is indeed a spectrum of insanity, and whilst monarchies can score high points with idiot rulers, institutions like democracy will always score highest.

There is much more to explore on this topic but further examination is beyond the scope of this essay. To do it justice, you should take the time to read Hoppe’s book in its entirety.

My goal is simply to look at the elements of emergent models of governance, monarchies being the most organic of all, and see how we can adapt them to a world in which Bitcoin exists. A world where taxation cannot easily be enforced, monetary inflation is impossible, monetary policy is a historic joke, legislation and bureaucracy are expensive, losses cannot be socialized, where citizens are customers, where fiscal prudence and responsibility are virtues that territory operators exhibit not through words, but necessary actions because there are no bailouts.

This is what I am interested in, and what we’ll explore as we proceed in this fourth installment.

My last words on monarchy in the section I shall leave to Frank Herbert, the visionary author of the Dune series:

“The pattern of monarchies and similar systems has a message of value for all political forms. My memories assure me that governments of any kind could profit from this message. Governments can be useful to the governed only so long as inherent tendencies toward tyranny are restrained. Monarchies have some good features beyond their star qualities.

“They can reduce the size and parasitic nature of the management bureaucracy.

“They can make speedy decisions when necessary. They fit an ancient human demand for a parental (tribal/feudal) hierarchy where every person knows his place. It is valuable to know your place, even if that place is temporary. It is galling to be held in place against your will. This is why I teach about tyranny in the best possible way by example.

“Even though you read these words after a passage of eons, my tyranny will not be forgotten. My Golden Path assures this. Knowing my message, I expect you to be exceedingly careful about the powers you delegate to any government.” — Leto The Tyrant; The Stolen Journals. “God Emperor of Dune.” by Frank Herbert

Socialism

We’ve spent an entire series on democracy, so there is no need to explore that model any further. Let us instead turn our attention to socialism. We all know that socialism’s many incarnations have failed, irrespective of whether they start with the c or the f word. Many of us even know why it fails, again and again, i.e.; it’s a ridiculous, anti-life, pro-entropy idea.

Despite this, there is an entire cohort of people out there calling themselves “progressive Bitcoiners” and even “socialist Bitcoiners.”

It’s baffling. So let’s clear something up:

Socialism CANNOT exist on a Bitcoin standard.

Bitcoin moves social order and operation onto an economic standard and the idea of a “socialist economy” is simply a contradiction in terms.

In order for an economy to exist, there must be calculation. In turn, there must exist both private property and decentralized information flow (the highest fidelity being the pricing engine of the free market) to derive the values from which to make these calculations.

In a socialist setting, this is impossible because allocations of resources are pre-ordained and there is no room for arithmetic calculation for the purpose of better utilization or economisation of resources, time or energy.

If no private property exists and no pricing can exist, then no form of calculation nor economisation can exist, meaning we are squarely in the realm of “politik.”

In that sense, socialism, communism and their collectivist cousins are all forms of economic regression and reversion to a form of primitivism. They have no place on a Bitcoin standard, which is fundamentally economic and evolutionary in nature.

Bitcoin is NOT political. It is raw, organic capitalism in action. It embodies both the static (e.g., immutable timechain), and the dynamic (e.g., mempool, the market). It is chaos which through an emergent, probabilistic process, creates order.

There is no central management or order by committee. The consequences of being on such a standard cannot be predetermined, nor can calculations be made for the economic actions of individuals constituting the greater system who each control the keys to their own wealth (their own private property).

There are irreconcilable inconsistencies at every layer, and as such, there cannot be socialist territories (at any scale beyond perhaps the Dunbar number) on a Bitcoin standard patchwork of city-states. We must think beyond these broken paradigms.

Anarchy And Anarchism

Anarchy, aka the “law of the jungle” is simultaneously the least understood and most vilified of all modes of human organization, despite being “the natural state of things.”

By virtue of living in modern cities, under “rule by government,” people believe we’ve somehow transcended the jungle, when in fact all we’ve done is transform it.

Just because we live in a statist paradigm, does not mean that those “states” do not compete on a macro-anarcho-paradigm (notwithstanding the push toward a centrally-managed globalist state in which jurisdictional arbitrage and experimentation is eroded).

The relationships between China, Russia, North Korea, the EU and the U.S., whilst at times seemingly coordinated, are actually anarchic. They operate in their own self-interest and will coordinate when it suits their own geo-political agendas – only their coordination or agendas presuppose the forced compliance of their citizenry. In other words, they operate in the realm of anarchy and we are forced to operate in the realm of slavery.

The following quote by Juvenal, nested in a quote by Edmund Burke, nested in a quote by Benjamin Marks, editor-in-chief at Economics.org.au sums this up nicely:

“Even absolute government fails to escape anarchy. The supreme judge has no superior authority; he is in a state of anarchy. Every criticism of anarchy in defense of government therefore fails, for no one ever governs the governors and we never really get out of anarchy; yet it is precisely for the combating of anarchy that government is defended. Edmund Burke called this the ‘grand error upon which all … legislative power is founded’:

“It was observed, that men had ungovernable passions, which made it necessary to guard against the violence they might offer to each other. They appointed governors over them for this reason; but a worse and more perplexing difficulty arises, how to be defended against the governors?

“‘Quis custodiet ipsos custodes?'”

[Juvenal’s “Who will govern the governors?]

Therein lies a big problem, and one that no amount of absolute government can ever solve; for the more absolute a government, the more tyrannical it becomes.

So if anarchy is inescapable, and merely comes in different flavors, shapes and sizes, what do we do?

First of all, recognize that it’s the natural state of things and that you’ve likely come into contact with it. Secondly, separate the organizing principle of “voluntarily-adopted rules,” from the more controversial “rejection of rulers.” You’ll quickly realize it’s neither scary, nor nuts.

Your local Sunday farmers’ market is a local example of anarchy, where self-interested vendors (irrespective of how friendly and altruistic they are toward each other) congregate to sell their goods without the need for some bureaucratic authority to tell them what to do.

All free markets are the same in fact. They stem from anarchy, and they find their own equilibrium without the need for some idiot bureaucrat to “regulate” it and get in the way.

The question is not ‘”how do we avoid that reality,” but “how do we live with it?”

The answer always lies in fostering stronger individuals, stronger communities and allowing the market to drive innovation in the protection and preservation of private property (the law). Humans and the groups they voluntarily form are perfectly capable of doing so in the absence of a monopoly on violence. We’ve been doing it long before “the State” arrived, and will do so long after it dissolves.

Bitcoin will once again enable anarchy at smaller scales so that humanity can flourish through competition and cooperation, not flounder through compulsion.

Of course, as we make this transition (as is the purpose of this series of essays) we will want to become acquainted with the different flavors of anarchy, and their modalities.

To begin with, we have “anarchism.”

As the name suggests it is an attempt to codify anarchy into a mode of coexistence. The core principle is that individual freedom can only be achieved if the power one can wield is limited to power over oneself. The boundary of one’s freedom is another’s property, and those who try to assume power over others face expulsion by the individuals making up said society.

The anarcho-capitalist variation is the same except it emphasizes the central importance of private property rights (the boundary and limitation) and the capitalist process (the driver for progress). Of all forms, this seems to be the most logically consistent and practical.

The anarcho-socialist version is like the three-wheeled vehicle, that’s neither tricycle, nor car, that neither works, nor is logically consistent. Don’t waste your time with such stupidity.

Voluntaryism, concerned more with interactions than power, is just the more “acceptable” version of anarchism. It recognises that a free and functional society is dependent upon the free and voluntary participation of the individuals constituting it — a principle deeply embodied in Bitcoin, and exhibited at your local farmers’ market.

Agorism is a more activist version of the theoretical anarchist modalities, where all relations between people are voluntary, but people also engage in counter-economic activities to minimize what they contribute to the state in the form of taxes, license fees, etc. I guess this is a more transitional modality, and perhaps less applicable on a Bitcoin standard. We shall see.

Note that the common thread in all of these logically consistent variations of anarchism is not the absence of rules, but specifically the absence of rulers.

Image source: Giamoco Zucco’s Twitter

This distinction is so important to note.

The cognitively-functional proponents of anarchism recognise that all games and forms of organization require rules, but they reject the idea of “rulers” who can change the rules, i.e., the elected or absolute kind. They know the state apparatus necessary for such rulers to rule virtually ensures that the most adept criminals just coalesce around it. Once hijacked, they can simply change the rules in their favor or force others to adopt rules they’ve concocted.

That is why stupidities like democracy always end up working against the very “citizens” who voted for it!

That is also why Mikhail Bakunin’s maxim is so accurate:

Anarchy is just the natural, voluntary organization of free, mature, responsible individuals who believe that the market can provide anything people need better, faster, cheaper, than the government can in its vacuum of economic consequence.

I know it’s hard for some people to come to terms with this simple reality. Maybe it’s because they’re internally inadequate and secretly yearn to be told what to do, or perhaps it’s a projection of their own desire to rule over others. Or a blend.

Whatever the case, people like Peter McCormack who criticize anarchy and the non-aggression principle (NAP) by calling failed states like Somalia, examples of “libertarianism” are moronic. Conflating the “protection of private property rights” with “the State” doesn’t make you edgy or “realistic.” It makes you uninformed.

The entire disagreement boils down to an inability to comprehend that an individual can defend themselves, nor that any other form of group or market-emergent organization can protect and preserve property rights.

Newsflash #1: Individuals are their best first responders.

Newsflash #2: The government sucks at protecting you.

Newsflash #3: The cornerstone of libertarianism and logically-consistent forms of anarchy is private property rights. The problem in Somalia is their complete absence! The necessary limitations and boundaries for peaceful coexistence are not present in failed states, where pure chaos reigns. There is no capitalist process. There is no private property. There is only theft and plunder, the very evils libertarians and anarcho-capitalists stand against.

So, no, Somalia is not libertarian, not anarchism, nor even anarchy. It is the blind, unhinged chaos of a failed state with no moral compass or rules.

I must quote Frederic Bastiat here again, as I have in previous parts of this series:

“[E]very time we object to a thing being done by government, [defenders of government intervention claim] that we object to its being done at all. We disapprove of education by the state — then we are against education altogether. We object to a state religion — then we would have no religion at all. We object to an equality which is brought about by the state then we are against equality, etc., etc. They might as well accuse us of wishing men not to eat, because we object to the cultivation of corn by the state.” — Frederic Bastiat, 1850

A monopoly on violence (such as the case in Somolia) does not fix this. It just gives the biggest thug the guns and the legal right to use them, then devolves into the institution where those we want to protect ourselves from congregate.

Instead of a robust society in which private property rights are first and foremost enforced by the individual, and then protected by a market of competitive providers, we end up with a bureaucratic apparatus that uses its monopoly to encroach upon the very property rights it was instantiated to protect.

An anarchist society is one which trends toward strength, resilience, independence and responsibility. It is smaller, nimbler and more values-aligned internally. All the services the state provides, from regulation, to licensing, to judicial, policing and defense can all be better provided by competitive private entities who are accountable to the customer and the market.

The only thing we do by centralizing these necessary services, and bestowing their provision to a monopoly is we give the criminals a crevice to initially hide, and then an apparatus to wield in “legally” perpetrating their crimes.

Localism

Localism is the natural antithesis to globalism.

It’s the idea that instead of one bureaucratic committee making decisions on behalf of larger and larger populations, that local bodies should govern local populations based on the unique cultures, values and ideas of their local territory.

In fact, I would include the unique terrain and resources of their local geography too.

The end goal for globalism is that one committee decides everything for everyone on the planet. Brainlets think this is a good idea because they view humans as linear entities to be plugged into a spreadsheet and simply shuffled around like numbers.

Localism, on the other hand, assumes complexity is the standard and recognises that diverse humans cannot be herded into one direction, under one directive, like mindless sheep.

Localism is built around the family unit and projects outward to the tribe (e.g., extended family, neighbors) and then community. By definition it does not scale beyond that which is “local,” because its mechanisms for trust are reputation and relationships. In other words it has a natural limiting factor in that it cannot work for populations large enough for reputations to get lost. Restraints to poor behavior naturally emerge as a way to ensure you’re not ejected from the local community or society.

In distinct contrast, large territories that encompass millions or even hundreds of millions of people, where the potential looters do not know their victims, and vice versa, the human desire to enrich oneself at another’s expense is subject to little or no restraint. Democracy is the pinnacle of this anti-achievement.

Democracy breaks down the family unit by replacing dependence on family bonds with dependence on the State. The government becomes the parent, the caretaker, the guardian, the nanny, the uncle, the aunt and in time, your overlord.

There’s a reason why terms like “Nanny State” and “Uncle Sam” have emerged to describe the apparatus of government.

Democracy is anti responsibility and attacks society at its very core and most important level; the individual. When you remove responsibility you transform individuals into infants. This process turns into a self-reinforcing downward spiral where the more infantile people become, the more they require a nanny state; and the greater the nanny state grows, the more infantilised individuals become.

This is what we’re seeing in society today. The masses have degenerated beyond the status of even sheeple and become real-life lemmings, marching right off the cliff.

Image source

Localism is a philosophy of responsibility, relationships, reputation and robust communities disavowing both reliance and dependence on large-scale government institutions.

It is not only more morally consistent because it allows humans to coalesce around similar values, creating internal homogeneity (peace) and external heterogeneity (diversity), but it is for similar reasons the only economically viable way to operate a territory. It’s like an extension of the “1000 true fans” idea from Kevin Kelly, or simply the idea of a niche. Niches are much more profitable. Mass market only remains viable insofar as the machinations of the state create Cantillon effects that enable zombie corporations and insiders to remain competitive by extraction, regulatory moats and access to free money.

Localism is the cure to globalism, but in order for it to be successful, there needs to be a cure for politics and statism first. There must exist unbreakable economic “bounds” which we’re all held accountable to by virtue of their existence. I don’t have to tell you by now what “fixes this.”

Localism and Bitcoin are compatible. In fact, they’re more than compatible; they’re like blood and body, or fish and ocean. For localism to work and not be destroyed by some bumbling bureaucratic fools (or bad actors), the cost of defending one’s wealth must be low, and the consequence for non-economic (i.e., politically deranged) behavior must be high and immediate.

Localism is the natural state, but the natural state cannot thrive, let alone survive when the artificial state envelopes, consumes and destroys everything around you.

Localism and large-scale governance modalities, like democracy, on the other hand are entirely incompatible.

We will get to localism in the end. The world must and will fragment. The only question is how do we get there?

Will we still have the infrastructure we’ve spent centuries building still available to us, or will we blow it all to pieces and wind up in a “localist” paradigm with technology no more sophisticated than the Amish … or worse.

My hope is that we fragment into city-states and transform the capital that is currently being wasted consciously. Local-scale governance seems to be where optimal economic performance will lie, alongside containing an optimal number of people to achieve both economies of scale without the diseconomies of scale notable in large scale cities, states or nation-states.

In Closing

Bitcoin is simultaneously voluntary, and essential.
It is both chaos and order. It is physical and metaphysical.

It’s a living, breathing paradox on so many levels.

It allows people to become sovereign over the product of their labor, arguably an extension of their property beyond their thoughts, ideas, body and family, which comes with ramifications that we’re yet to truly fathom.

It gives people a choice to create what they want with their wealth and experiment with new forms of cooperation, governance and coexistence, which will inevitably lead to both successful and failed experiments.

We will simultaneously see anarchy, small-scale communes, new forms of hierarchical order and quite possibly an age of modern monarchies; which we shall explore in Part Five.

Some of you may want to prove me wrong and build a communist or socialist utopia on a Bitcoin standard, one day.

And by all means, if you want to go ahead and build a city in which you ask that members share their wealth around by the will of some form of centrally-managed committee, go for it. I don’t think many people will stay, but you’re free to try it out.

The whole point of Bitcoin is to make forced collectivism impossible.

What succeeds in the end I do not know, but based on principles of what we’ve discussed in this series, and the works by the greats we’ve quoted, we can make some assumptions.

I want to close this out with something for you to ponder before the fifth and final installment of the series…

The Mob

I was in an Uber in Las Vegas last week and the driver said the most interesting thing …

There was a shooting at a shopping center nearby the location he was dropping us off at. He told us to be careful and then offhandedly said:

“This would never have happened while the mob ran the place.”

I found this profoundly interesting. Here was clearly a conservative man, probably in his mid-fifties, pro “law and order,” advocating for … the mob?

I asked him about who runs Vegas these days. He responded (I’m paraphrasing):

“The corporate mob came and took over from the old mob. The old guys aren’t allowed anywhere near here anymore, and the guys who took over don’t give a crap.”

This gentleman recognised “the mob” was an institution of law and order, and although he may not have articulated it this way, because the OG mob was economically accountable (i.e., they couldn’t print or tax their way out of a mistake), the services they rendered were far superior to those their broken government of Las Vegas currently offers.

This is consistent with the idea that the government is simply the biggest “mob,” with the most gun-wielding thugs. They win not because they’re the best, but because they’re able to fund themselves through the most widespread forms of theft (taxation and inflation) and obtain the subsequent “monopoly on violence” to solidify their power.

Knowing this, the most adept criminals simply adopt the maxim, “If you can’t beat ’em, join ’em.”

This is why governments and legal monopolies of any kind are so dangerous. They become the very thing they were instituted to protect us from.

I later reflected on his comments, and it reminded me of James Dale Davidson and William Rees-Mogg’s “Sovereign Individual.” Throughout the book, they point out the rise of mobs and gangs against the backdrop of the failing state. As power structures crumble, new entrants will emerge to fill those voids.

I wonder what the changing world order will look like as criminals realize the ideal apparatus for theft is no longer the state? Will they rise up once again and muscle in?

How will mobs form on an emergent Bitcoin standard?

Will these territories be run in fact, by economically accountable “mobs” who offer protection services at a fairer market rate than the current governments we are subject to?

Will the families that run these mobs resemble mini-monarchies?

I don’t know, but chaos will surely ensue until a new, stable anarchy is achieved.

Until next time …

This is a guest post by Aleks Svetski, Author of The UnCommunist Manifesto, The Bitcoin Times and Host of anchor.fm/WakeUpPod. Opinions expressed are entirely their own and do not necessarily reflect those of BTC Inc or Bitcoin Magazine.

Read More

With each new installment of this series, the Clown World simulation takes it up a notch.

Part Three kicked off with the stupidity happening in Canada.

Part Four is now being written right in the midst of a geopolitical clusterfuck in which every side is lying, maneuvering and propagandizing, while innocent individuals who just want to live in peace are being terrorized, displaced and killed.

Anyone who still has faith in modern “governments” of any kind at this point is beyond help.

This madness is all a function of the “representative state.” I don’t care if it’s Russia, NATO, the U.S., the EU or Ukraine itself. None of these entities are innocent. Only the individuals and families living within their bullshit borders are.

Volodymyr Zelensky is just as guilty as Vladimir Putin. He and his recently-discovered $1.2 billion in an offshore account, are a prime example of how “democratically elected representatives” simply use the very people they’re supposed to serve, for their own ends. Whilst innocent people die, he’s posing for photos, making deals with other politicians and literally acting with Sean Penn. While his people are locked out of the financial system, he and his cronies’ salaries are being paid by the wealth confiscated via taxes from those same people.

None of the decision-makers, on any side, are actually being displaced, killed, shot at or experiencing the destruction of their livelihoods. The talking heads, politicians and so-called “human rights” charlatans like Garry Kasparov, are openly calling for war because they have NO personal skin in the game.

The only human rights these frauds believe in are the ones they get funded to turn into propaganda. And they’ll play hawk over social media like little keyboard warriors, in the hopes to spark a larger war so that they can point the finger and say: “See. I was right.”

Absolute egomaniacs.

Hey Kasparov, if you want war, how about you go fight it yourself?

This continued madness is all a function of “rulers” and their pet “presenters” experiencing no consequence for their actions. If anything, the only “consequence” is personal enrichment.

The ends which they play all of these games for just happen to include you and I as expendable pawns, and when the price for one’s enrichment is somebody else’s blood, you can be almost certain that blood will be spilled.

The following passage from Nassim Taleb’s “Skin in the Game” shines an abundantly clear light on this, and reminds us why the current version of madness in Russia/Ukraine (or for that matter, any other modern war) not only exists, but why it’s in fact a historical aberration:

“…owning one’s risk was an inescapable moral code for the past four millennia, until very recent times. Warmongers were required to be warriors. Fewer than a third of Roman emperors died in their bed (assuming those weren’t skillfully poisoned). Status came with increased exposure to risk: Alexander, Hannibal, Scipio, and Napoleon were not only first in battle, but derived their authority from a disproportionate exhibition of courage in previous campaigns. Courage is the only virtue that can’t be faked (or gamed like metrics). Lords and knights were individuals who traded their courage for status, as their social contract was an obligation to protect those who granted them their status. This primacy of the risk-taker, whether warrior (or, critically, merchant), prevailed almost all the time in almost every human civilization; exceptions, such as Pharaonic Egypt or Ming China, in which the bureaucrat-scholar moved to the top of the pecking order were followed by collapse.” — Nassim Taleb

We’ll expand on this in the “Monarchies” section below, but suffice it to say that you won’t see these representatives bring the battle to their doorstep. They’ll be sending emails from their cushy home-office in the Hamptons while drawing a salary, paid for by you, and receiving “donations” from the cronies currently profiteering.

In fact, that’s the worst part of this entire madness. Modern governments continue to play these games because we’re not only stupid enough to assign them that “right,” but we also pay them for it!

Should we make it through the Great Filter, our descendants will shake their heads at the stupidity that non-economic, democratic governance was.

I look forward to an age where responsibility and consequence are reintroduced, where power is concentrated in distributed, competitive nodes, and democracy is but a memory. I have faith that Bitcoin will accomplish that, and change the course of human development “forever … Laura … forever.”

Monarchies

Skin in the game is what makes monarchies superior to democracies, or any other modern, representative-run state.

The point illustrated above by Taleb makes a resounding case for monarchy > democracy alone, but let us delve further:

Monarchies, in the more traditional sense (not so much the lizardry of modernity) are run by a private property owner (albeit a large one). As a result, their property is their capital and its preservation is naturally incentivised. Yes, a moron monarch may make poor decisions and burn through the capital in exchange for “present cash flow,” but the base tendency is otherwise. The converse is true for representative dEmOcRaCiEs as we outlined in parts One and Two of the series.The hereditary nature of monarchies is also an advantage. It’s a localized concentration of power more easily held accountable, and when combined with private property incentives, should produce more just “leaders” than the popularity contest winners in a democracy who will lie, cheat, steal and do anything to get into power.Numbers 1 and 2 above combined with skin in the game incline monarchs toward longer-term decision-making for the preservation of their private property, for their economic viability and for the continuation of their hereditary lineage. This lower time preference and proximity to economic consequences create a superior environment for sensible monetary policy, taxation and legislation (notwithstanding the inherent stupidity of all three).

These factors remind me of a passage from Hans-Herman Hoppe’s; “Democracy, The God That Failed.”

“Historically, the selection of a prince was through the accident of his noble birth, and his only personal qualification was typically his upbringing as a future prince and preserver of the dynasty and its status and possessions. This did not assure that a prince would not be bad and dangerous, of course. However, it is worth remembering that any prince who failed in his primary duty of preserving the dynasty, who wrecked or ruined the country, caused civil unrest, turmoil and strife, or otherwise endangered the position of the dynasty faced the immediate risk of either being neutralized or assassinated by another member of his own family.

“On the flip side, with a strong education and a princely upbringing, a monarch was far more inclined to be a functional ruler than the kind of character who rises through the political ranks of a democracy.” — Hoppe

Note that like Hoppe, I neither suggest we go back to monarchies, nor defend taxation, monetary policy or legislation of any kind. I merely present it here to compare the natural tendencies present in monarchies versus democracies (or other representative governments).

There is indeed a spectrum of insanity, and whilst monarchies can score high points with idiot rulers, institutions like democracy will always score highest.

There is much more to explore on this topic but further examination is beyond the scope of this essay. To do it justice, you should take the time to read Hoppe’s book in its entirety.

My goal is simply to look at the elements of emergent models of governance, monarchies being the most organic of all, and see how we can adapt them to a world in which Bitcoin exists. A world where taxation cannot easily be enforced, monetary inflation is impossible, monetary policy is a historic joke, legislation and bureaucracy are expensive, losses cannot be socialized, where citizens are customers, where fiscal prudence and responsibility are virtues that territory operators exhibit not through words, but necessary actions because there are no bailouts.

This is what I am interested in, and what we’ll explore as we proceed in this fourth installment.

My last words on monarchy in the section I shall leave to Frank Herbert, the visionary author of the Dune series:

“The pattern of monarchies and similar systems has a message of value for all political forms. My memories assure me that governments of any kind could profit from this message. Governments can be useful to the governed only so long as inherent tendencies toward tyranny are restrained. Monarchies have some good features beyond their star qualities.

“They can reduce the size and parasitic nature of the management bureaucracy.

“They can make speedy decisions when necessary. They fit an ancient human demand for a parental (tribal/feudal) hierarchy where every person knows his place. It is valuable to know your place, even if that place is temporary. It is galling to be held in place against your will. This is why I teach about tyranny in the best possible way by example.

“Even though you read these words after a passage of eons, my tyranny will not be forgotten. My Golden Path assures this. Knowing my message, I expect you to be exceedingly careful about the powers you delegate to any government.” — Leto The Tyrant; The Stolen Journals. “God Emperor of Dune.” by Frank Herbert

We’ve spent an entire series on democracy, so there is no need to explore that model any further. Let us instead turn our attention to socialism. We all know that socialism’s many incarnations have failed, irrespective of whether they start with the c or the f word. Many of us even know why it fails, again and again, i.e.; it’s a ridiculous, anti-life, pro-entropy idea.

Despite this, there is an entire cohort of people out there calling themselves “progressive Bitcoiners” and even “socialist Bitcoiners.”

It’s baffling. So let’s clear something up:

Socialism CANNOT exist on a Bitcoin standard.

Bitcoin moves social order and operation onto an economic standard and the idea of a “socialist economy” is simply a contradiction in terms.

In order for an economy to exist, there must be calculation. In turn, there must exist both private property and decentralized information flow (the highest fidelity being the pricing engine of the free market) to derive the values from which to make these calculations.

In a socialist setting, this is impossible because allocations of resources are pre-ordained and there is no room for arithmetic calculation for the purpose of better utilization or economisation of resources, time or energy.

If no private property exists and no pricing can exist, then no form of calculation nor economisation can exist, meaning we are squarely in the realm of “politik.”

In that sense, socialism, communism and their collectivist cousins are all forms of economic regression and reversion to a form of primitivism. They have no place on a Bitcoin standard, which is fundamentally economic and evolutionary in nature.

Bitcoin is NOT political. It is raw, organic capitalism in action. It embodies both the static (e.g., immutable timechain), and the dynamic (e.g., mempool, the market). It is chaos which through an emergent, probabilistic process, creates order.

There is no central management or order by committee. The consequences of being on such a standard cannot be predetermined, nor can calculations be made for the economic actions of individuals constituting the greater system who each control the keys to their own wealth (their own private property).

There are irreconcilable inconsistencies at every layer, and as such, there cannot be socialist territories (at any scale beyond perhaps the Dunbar number) on a Bitcoin standard patchwork of city-states. We must think beyond these broken paradigms.

Anarchy And Anarchism

Anarchy, aka the “law of the jungle” is simultaneously the least understood and most vilified of all modes of human organization, despite being “the natural state of things.”

By virtue of living in modern cities, under “rule by government,” people believe we’ve somehow transcended the jungle, when in fact all we’ve done is transform it.

Just because we live in a statist paradigm, does not mean that those “states” do not compete on a macro-anarcho-paradigm (notwithstanding the push toward a centrally-managed globalist state in which jurisdictional arbitrage and experimentation is eroded).

The relationships between China, Russia, North Korea, the EU and the U.S., whilst at times seemingly coordinated, are actually anarchic. They operate in their own self-interest and will coordinate when it suits their own geo-political agendas – only their coordination or agendas presuppose the forced compliance of their citizenry. In other words, they operate in the realm of anarchy and we are forced to operate in the realm of slavery.

The following quote by Juvenal, nested in a quote by Edmund Burke, nested in a quote by Benjamin Marks, editor-in-chief at Economics.org.au sums this up nicely:

“Even absolute government fails to escape anarchy. The supreme judge has no superior authority; he is in a state of anarchy. Every criticism of anarchy in defense of government therefore fails, for no one ever governs the governors and we never really get out of anarchy; yet it is precisely for the combating of anarchy that government is defended. Edmund Burke called this the ‘grand error upon which all … legislative power is founded’:

“It was observed, that men had ungovernable passions, which made it necessary to guard against the violence they might offer to each other. They appointed governors over them for this reason; but a worse and more perplexing difficulty arises, how to be defended against the governors?

“‘Quis custodiet ipsos custodes?'”

[Juvenal’s “Who will govern the governors?]

Therein lies a big problem, and one that no amount of absolute government can ever solve; for the more absolute a government, the more tyrannical it becomes.

So if anarchy is inescapable, and merely comes in different flavors, shapes and sizes, what do we do?

First of all, recognize that it’s the natural state of things and that you’ve likely come into contact with it. Secondly, separate the organizing principle of “voluntarily-adopted rules,” from the more controversial “rejection of rulers.” You’ll quickly realize it’s neither scary, nor nuts.

Your local Sunday farmers’ market is a local example of anarchy, where self-interested vendors (irrespective of how friendly and altruistic they are toward each other) congregate to sell their goods without the need for some bureaucratic authority to tell them what to do.

All free markets are the same in fact. They stem from anarchy, and they find their own equilibrium without the need for some idiot bureaucrat to “regulate” it and get in the way.

The question is not ‘”how do we avoid that reality,” but “how do we live with it?”

The answer always lies in fostering stronger individuals, stronger communities and allowing the market to drive innovation in the protection and preservation of private property (the law). Humans and the groups they voluntarily form are perfectly capable of doing so in the absence of a monopoly on violence. We’ve been doing it long before “the State” arrived, and will do so long after it dissolves.

Bitcoin will once again enable anarchy at smaller scales so that humanity can flourish through competition and cooperation, not flounder through compulsion.

Of course, as we make this transition (as is the purpose of this series of essays) we will want to become acquainted with the different flavors of anarchy, and their modalities.

To begin with, we have “anarchism.”

As the name suggests it is an attempt to codify anarchy into a mode of coexistence. The core principle is that individual freedom can only be achieved if the power one can wield is limited to power over oneself. The boundary of one’s freedom is another’s property, and those who try to assume power over others face expulsion by the individuals making up said society.

The anarcho-capitalist variation is the same except it emphasizes the central importance of private property rights (the boundary and limitation) and the capitalist process (the driver for progress). Of all forms, this seems to be the most logically consistent and practical.

The anarcho-socialist version is like the three-wheeled vehicle, that’s neither tricycle, nor car, that neither works, nor is logically consistent. Don’t waste your time with such stupidity.

Voluntaryism, concerned more with interactions than power, is just the more “acceptable” version of anarchism. It recognises that a free and functional society is dependent upon the free and voluntary participation of the individuals constituting it — a principle deeply embodied in Bitcoin, and exhibited at your local farmers’ market.

Agorism is a more activist version of the theoretical anarchist modalities, where all relations between people are voluntary, but people also engage in counter-economic activities to minimize what they contribute to the state in the form of taxes, license fees, etc. I guess this is a more transitional modality, and perhaps less applicable on a Bitcoin standard. We shall see.

Note that the common thread in all of these logically consistent variations of anarchism is not the absence of rules, but specifically the absence of rulers.

This distinction is so important to note.

The cognitively-functional proponents of anarchism recognise that all games and forms of organization require rules, but they reject the idea of “rulers” who can change the rules, i.e., the elected or absolute kind. They know the state apparatus necessary for such rulers to rule virtually ensures that the most adept criminals just coalesce around it. Once hijacked, they can simply change the rules in their favor or force others to adopt rules they’ve concocted.

That is why stupidities like democracy always end up working against the very “citizens” who voted for it!

That is also why Mikhail Bakunin’s maxim is so accurate:

Anarchy is just the natural, voluntary organization of free, mature, responsible individuals who believe that the market can provide anything people need better, faster, cheaper, than the government can in its vacuum of economic consequence.

I know it’s hard for some people to come to terms with this simple reality. Maybe it’s because they’re internally inadequate and secretly yearn to be told what to do, or perhaps it’s a projection of their own desire to rule over others. Or a blend.

Whatever the case, people like Peter McCormack who criticize anarchy and the non-aggression principle (NAP) by calling failed states like Somalia, examples of “libertarianism” are moronic. Conflating the “protection of private property rights” with “the State” doesn’t make you edgy or “realistic.” It makes you uninformed.

The entire disagreement boils down to an inability to comprehend that an individual can defend themselves, nor that any other form of group or market-emergent organization can protect and preserve property rights.

Newsflash #1: Individuals are their best first responders.

Newsflash #2: The government sucks at protecting you.

Newsflash #3: The cornerstone of libertarianism and logically-consistent forms of anarchy is private property rights. The problem in Somalia is their complete absence! The necessary limitations and boundaries for peaceful coexistence are not present in failed states, where pure chaos reigns. There is no capitalist process. There is no private property. There is only theft and plunder, the very evils libertarians and anarcho-capitalists stand against.

So, no, Somalia is not libertarian, not anarchism, nor even anarchy. It is the blind, unhinged chaos of a failed state with no moral compass or rules.

I must quote Frederic Bastiat here again, as I have in previous parts of this series:

“[E]very time we object to a thing being done by government, [defenders of government intervention claim] that we object to its being done at all. We disapprove of education by the state — then we are against education altogether. We object to a state religion — then we would have no religion at all. We object to an equality which is brought about by the state then we are against equality, etc., etc. They might as well accuse us of wishing men not to eat, because we object to the cultivation of corn by the state.” — Frederic Bastiat, 1850

A monopoly on violence (such as the case in Somolia) does not fix this. It just gives the biggest thug the guns and the legal right to use them, then devolves into the institution where those we want to protect ourselves from congregate.

Instead of a robust society in which private property rights are first and foremost enforced by the individual, and then protected by a market of competitive providers, we end up with a bureaucratic apparatus that uses its monopoly to encroach upon the very property rights it was instantiated to protect.

An anarchist society is one which trends toward strength, resilience, independence and responsibility. It is smaller, nimbler and more values-aligned internally. All the services the state provides, from regulation, to licensing, to judicial, policing and defense can all be better provided by competitive private entities who are accountable to the customer and the market.

The only thing we do by centralizing these necessary services, and bestowing their provision to a monopoly is we give the criminals a crevice to initially hide, and then an apparatus to wield in “legally” perpetrating their crimes.

Localism

Localism is the natural antithesis to globalism.

It’s the idea that instead of one bureaucratic committee making decisions on behalf of larger and larger populations, that local bodies should govern local populations based on the unique cultures, values and ideas of their local territory.

In fact, I would include the unique terrain and resources of their local geography too.

The end goal for globalism is that one committee decides everything for everyone on the planet. Brainlets think this is a good idea because they view humans as linear entities to be plugged into a spreadsheet and simply shuffled around like numbers.

Localism, on the other hand, assumes complexity is the standard and recognises that diverse humans cannot be herded into one direction, under one directive, like mindless sheep.

Localism is built around the family unit and projects outward to the tribe (e.g., extended family, neighbors) and then community. By definition it does not scale beyond that which is “local,” because its mechanisms for trust are reputation and relationships. In other words it has a natural limiting factor in that it cannot work for populations large enough for reputations to get lost. Restraints to poor behavior naturally emerge as a way to ensure you’re not ejected from the local community or society.

In distinct contrast, large territories that encompass millions or even hundreds of millions of people, where the potential looters do not know their victims, and vice versa, the human desire to enrich oneself at another’s expense is subject to little or no restraint. Democracy is the pinnacle of this anti-achievement.

Democracy breaks down the family unit by replacing dependence on family bonds with dependence on the State. The government becomes the parent, the caretaker, the guardian, the nanny, the uncle, the aunt and in time, your overlord.

There’s a reason why terms like “Nanny State” and “Uncle Sam” have emerged to describe the apparatus of government.

Democracy is anti responsibility and attacks society at its very core and most important level; the individual. When you remove responsibility you transform individuals into infants. This process turns into a self-reinforcing downward spiral where the more infantile people become, the more they require a nanny state; and the greater the nanny state grows, the more infantilised individuals become.

This is what we’re seeing in society today. The masses have degenerated beyond the status of even sheeple and become real-life lemmings, marching right off the cliff.

Localism is a philosophy of responsibility, relationships, reputation and robust communities disavowing both reliance and dependence on large-scale government institutions.

It is not only more morally consistent because it allows humans to coalesce around similar values, creating internal homogeneity (peace) and external heterogeneity (diversity), but it is for similar reasons the only economically viable way to operate a territory. It’s like an extension of the “1000 true fans” idea from Kevin Kelly, or simply the idea of a niche. Niches are much more profitable. Mass market only remains viable insofar as the machinations of the state create Cantillon effects that enable zombie corporations and insiders to remain competitive by extraction, regulatory moats and access to free money.

Localism is the cure to globalism, but in order for it to be successful, there needs to be a cure for politics and statism first. There must exist unbreakable economic “bounds” which we’re all held accountable to by virtue of their existence. I don’t have to tell you by now what “fixes this.”

Localism and Bitcoin are compatible. In fact, they’re more than compatible; they’re like blood and body, or fish and ocean. For localism to work and not be destroyed by some bumbling bureaucratic fools (or bad actors), the cost of defending one’s wealth must be low, and the consequence for non-economic (i.e., politically deranged) behavior must be high and immediate.

Localism is the natural state, but the natural state cannot thrive, let alone survive when the artificial state envelopes, consumes and destroys everything around you.

Localism and large-scale governance modalities, like democracy, on the other hand are entirely incompatible.

We will get to localism in the end. The world must and will fragment. The only question is how do we get there?

Will we still have the infrastructure we’ve spent centuries building still available to us, or will we blow it all to pieces and wind up in a “localist” paradigm with technology no more sophisticated than the Amish … or worse.

My hope is that we fragment into city-states and transform the capital that is currently being wasted consciously. Local-scale governance seems to be where optimal economic performance will lie, alongside containing an optimal number of people to achieve both economies of scale without the diseconomies of scale notable in large scale cities, states or nation-states.

In Closing

Bitcoin is simultaneously voluntary, and essential.
It is both chaos and order. It is physical and metaphysical.

It’s a living, breathing paradox on so many levels.

It allows people to become sovereign over the product of their labor, arguably an extension of their property beyond their thoughts, ideas, body and family, which comes with ramifications that we’re yet to truly fathom.

It gives people a choice to create what they want with their wealth and experiment with new forms of cooperation, governance and coexistence, which will inevitably lead to both successful and failed experiments.

We will simultaneously see anarchy, small-scale communes, new forms of hierarchical order and quite possibly an age of modern monarchies; which we shall explore in Part Five.

Some of you may want to prove me wrong and build a communist or socialist utopia on a Bitcoin standard, one day.

And by all means, if you want to go ahead and build a city in which you ask that members share their wealth around by the will of some form of centrally-managed committee, go for it. I don’t think many people will stay, but you’re free to try it out.

The whole point of Bitcoin is to make forced collectivism impossible.

What succeeds in the end I do not know, but based on principles of what we’ve discussed in this series, and the works by the greats we’ve quoted, we can make some assumptions.

I want to close this out with something for you to ponder before the fifth and final installment of the series…

The Mob

I was in an Uber in Las Vegas last week and the driver said the most interesting thing …

There was a shooting at a shopping center nearby the location he was dropping us off at. He told us to be careful and then offhandedly said:

“This would never have happened while the mob ran the place.”

I found this profoundly interesting. Here was clearly a conservative man, probably in his mid-fifties, pro “law and order,” advocating for … the mob?

I asked him about who runs Vegas these days. He responded (I’m paraphrasing):

“The corporate mob came and took over from the old mob. The old guys aren’t allowed anywhere near here anymore, and the guys who took over don’t give a crap.”

This gentleman recognised “the mob” was an institution of law and order, and although he may not have articulated it this way, because the OG mob was economically accountable (i.e., they couldn’t print or tax their way out of a mistake), the services they rendered were far superior to those their broken government of Las Vegas currently offers.

This is consistent with the idea that the government is simply the biggest “mob,” with the most gun-wielding thugs. They win not because they’re the best, but because they’re able to fund themselves through the most widespread forms of theft (taxation and inflation) and obtain the subsequent “monopoly on violence” to solidify their power.

Knowing this, the most adept criminals simply adopt the maxim, “If you can’t beat ’em, join ’em.”

This is why governments and legal monopolies of any kind are so dangerous. They become the very thing they were instituted to protect us from.

I later reflected on his comments, and it reminded me of James Dale Davidson and William Rees-Mogg’s “Sovereign Individual.” Throughout the book, they point out the rise of mobs and gangs against the backdrop of the failing state. As power structures crumble, new entrants will emerge to fill those voids.

I wonder what the changing world order will look like as criminals realize the ideal apparatus for theft is no longer the state? Will they rise up once again and muscle in?

How will mobs form on an emergent Bitcoin standard?

Will these territories be run in fact, by economically accountable “mobs” who offer protection services at a fairer market rate than the current governments we are subject to?

Will the families that run these mobs resemble mini-monarchies?

I don’t know, but chaos will surely ensue until a new, stable anarchy is achieved.

Until next time …

This is a guest post by Aleks Svetski, Author of The UnCommunist Manifesto, The Bitcoin Times and Host of anchor.fm/WakeUpPod. Opinions expressed are entirely their own and do not necessarily reflect those of BTC Inc or Bitcoin Magazine.

Feedzy

Recent Posts

Ether Favored in Crypto Rotation as Bitcoin Recoils Off $100K Sell Wall

After a prolonged downtrend relative to bitcoin (BTC), Ethereum's ether (ETH) is showing signs of…

34 minutes ago

Bitcoin Slides Near $94K, but Short-Term Bullish Target of $100K BTC Unchanged

A bitcoin (BTC)-led crypto market correction continued into its third day as the asset lost…

34 minutes ago

3 Reasons Why Bitcoin Risks Falling Below $90K: Godbole

Bitcoin's (BTC) much-anticipated breakout above $100,000 remains out of reach, with prices retreating to $94,500…

34 minutes ago

Bitcoin Long-Term Holders Have 163K More BTC to Sell, History Indicates: Van Straten

Bitcoin (BTC) has dropped 7.6% since it almost — but not quite — touched the…

34 minutes ago

First Mover Americas: Bitcoin’s Correction Takes Price Below $93K

Starting next Monday, First Mover Americas will become Crypto Daybook Americas, your new morning briefing…

35 minutes ago

This Hedge Fund Now Has a 1,000x Profit on Bitcoin

Pantera Capital Management’s Bitcoin Fund just hit a milestone: a 1,000-fold gain in the value…

35 minutes ago